Mutual Coordination Economics Working Group: Difference between revisions

From P2P Foundation
Jump to navigation Jump to search
 
(27 intermediate revisions by 2 users not shown)
Line 3: Line 3:
Alternative Name: Cybernetic Economics
Alternative Name: Cybernetic Economics


=Discussion=
=Name of the Group=


==Name of the Group==
'''1. David Potocnik:'''
 
'''1. [[David Potocnik]]:'''


"My original intention was to form a study group & redevelopment project on the ashes of the Cybersyn project.
"My original intention was to form a study group & redevelopment project on the ashes of the Cybersyn project.
Line 22: Line 20:




'''2. Michel Bauwens:'''
'''2. [[Michel Bauwens]]:'''


I have no objection to changing the name.  
I have no objection to changing the name.  
Line 33: Line 31:
=Participants=
=Participants=


* [[Jean-Daniel Cusin]]
* [[Angela Espinosa]]
* [[Angela Espinosa]]
* [[Lynn Foster]]
* [[Lynn Foster]]
* [[Bob Haugen]]
* [[Bob Haugen]]
* [[David Potocnik]]
* [https://twitter.com/dcht00 David Potočnik]
* [[Enrique Rivera]]
* Enrique Rivera
* [[Jon Walker]]
* Jon Walker
 
=Other Researchers=
 
* [[Raul Espejo]], former director of the cybersyn project, now living in Lincoln UK; http://www.syncho.com/
 
 
=Discussion=
 
==Introduction to the potential for [[Mutual Coordination of Physical Production through Peer Production]]==
 
 
0. '''What market pricing is to capitalism and planning is to state-based production, mutual coordination is to commons-based peer production!'''
 
1. Today we have the emergence of a new proto-system of production, [[Commons-Based Peer Production]] in which contributors are free to contribute to a common pool of shareable knowledge, code and design, which may be associated through physical production in microfactories using distributed machinery such as 3D printing.
 
2. This emerging new system of value creation and distribution is not sustainable if contributors need to find work as labour for capital, so contributors need to be able to generate livelihoods for themselves, keeping the generation of surplus value within the sphere of the commons and its contributors.
 
3. To achieve this, we advocate the use of [[Commons-Based Reciprocity Licenses]] such as the [[Peer Production License]]. This allows for the creation of a non-capitalist 'counter' economy based on [[Open Cooperativism]] and other forms of an ethical economy. In this proposal, the commoners or peer producers, i.e. the contributors to the commons, are also cooperators of their own corporate entities, which create livelihoods and insure the surplus value remains within the commons. So, in between the sphere of the accumulation of the commons (open input, participatory process, commons-oriented output), and the sphere of capital accumulation, there is a intermediary sphere of cooperative production, which regulates physical production and the social reproduction of the commoners-cooperators.
 
 
4. The production of immaterial common pools is already regulated through mutual coordination and stigmergy, i.e. coordination based on open and transparent signals of what is needed by the system; but physical production cannot be coordinated without similar signals, i.e. the coordination of production through information. It is therefore a next logical step to advocate and practice, within the ethical entrepreneurial coalitions that coalesce around particular commons through their shared adherence to the commons-based licenses, to also practice open accounting and open supply-chains and logistics. This means that within these coalitions, physical production can also be coordinated through stigmergic signals; and negotiated coordination and even voluntary common planning can take place on the basis of the shared production information.
 
=Typology of Other Approaches=
 
Compiled and commented upon by Bob Haugen:
 
==Parecon: Participatory Economics==
 
From Wikipedia [http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Participatory_economics]:
 
Participatory economics, often abbreviated parecon, is an economic system based on participatory decision making as the primary economic mechanism for the allocation of the factors of production and guidance of production in a given society. Participatory decision-making involves the participation of all persons in decision-making on issues in proportion to the impact such decisions have on their lives. Participatory economics is a form of decentralized economic planning and socialism involving the common ownership of the means of production. The participatory economic system is proposed as an alternative to contemporary capitalism, as well as an alternative to central planning. This economic model is primarily associated with the proposals put forth by the political theorist Michael Albert and economist Robin Hahnel, who describe participatory economics as an anarchistic economic vision.
 
The underlying values that parecon seeks to implement are equity, solidarity, diversity, workers' self-management and efficiency (defined as accomplishing goals without wasting valued assets). The institutions of parecon include workers' and consumers' councils utilizing self-managerial methods for making decisions,balanced job complexes, remuneration based on individual effort, and participatory planning.
 
[...]
 
Albert and Hahnel argue that it is inequitable and ineffective to compensate people on the basis of their birth or heredity. Therefore, the primary principle of participatory economics is to reward for effort and sacrifice.[3] For example, mining work — which is dangerous and uncomfortable — would be more highly paid than office work for the same amount of time, thus allowing the miner to work fewer hours for the same pay, and the burden of highly dangerous and strenuous jobs to be shared among the populace.
 
Additionally, participatory economics would provide exemptions from the compensation for effort principle.[3] People with disabilities who are unable to work, children, the elderly, the infirm and workers who are legitimately in transitional circumstances, can be remunerated according to need. However, every able adult has the obligation to perform some socially useful work as a requirement for receiving reward, albeit in the context of a society providing free health care, education, skills training, and the freedom to choose between various democratically structured workplaces with jobs balanced for desirability and empowerment.
The starting point for the income of all workers in participatory economics is an equal share of the social product. From this point, incomes for personal expenditures and consumption rights for public goods can be expected to diverge by small degrees reflecting the choices that individual workers make in striking a balance between work and leisure time, and reflecting the level of danger and strenuousness of a job as assigned by their immediate peers.
 
 
 
==[[New Socialism]]==
 
Source: [http://www.amazon.com/Towards-New-Socialism-Paul-Cockshott/dp/0851245455/]
 
As described by Nick Dyer-Witheford in [[Red Plenty Platforms]] : [http://blog.p2pfoundation.net/why-you-should-read-the-essay-red-plenty-platforms/2013/08/20]
 
...its twenty-first century super-computer planning follows to the letter the logic of the late nineteenth century Critique of the Gotha Program (Marx, 1970), which famously suggests that at the first, ‘lower’ stage to communism, before
conditions of abundance allow ‘to each according to his needs’, remuneration will be determined by the hours of socially necessary labour required to produce goods and services. In the capitalist workplace, workers are paid for the reproduction of the capacity to labour, rather than for the labour actually extracted from them; it is this that enables the capitalist to secure surplus value.
 
The elimination of this state of affairs, Cockshott and Cottrell contend, requires nothing less than the abolition of money—that is, the elimination of the fungible general medium of exchange that, through a series of metamorphoses of money in and out of the commodity form, creates the self-expanding value that is capital. In their new Socialism, work would be remunerated in labour certificates; an hour’s work could be exchanged for goods taking, on a socially average basis, an equivalent time to produce. The certificates would be extinguished in this exchange; they would not circulate, and could not be used for speculation. Because workers would be paid the full social value of their labour, there would be no owner profits, and no capitalists to direct resource allocation.  Workers would, however, be taxed to establish a pool of labour-time resources available for social investments made by planning boards whose mandate would be set by democratic decisions on overall social goals.
 
[...]
 
Cockshott and Cottrell’s answer [to the Calculation Problem] involves new tools, both conceptual and technical. The theoretical advances are drawn from branches of computing science that deal with abbreviating the number of discrete steps needed to complete a calculation. Such analysis, they suggest, shows their opponents’ objections are based on ‘pathologically inefficient’ methods (Cockshott, in Shalizi, 2012).
 
The input-output structure of the economy is, they point out, ‘sparse’—that is to say, only a small fraction of the goods are directly used to produce any other good. Not everything is an input for everything else: yogurt is not used to produce steel. The majority of the equations invoked to suggest insuperable complexity are therefore gratuitous. An algorithm can be designed to short-cut through input-output tables, ignoring blank entries, iteratively repeating the process until it arrives at a result of an acceptable order of accuracy.
 
Shalizi takes up Cockshott’s proposals in another article responding to the criticisms of the first article cited above:
 
For Cockshott's algorithm, or any other linear solver, to be of real relevance here, we need to presume that
 
* we have settled on exactly how much of every good (and service) we want the economy to produce, including indexing by time and space;
 
* we have, for each good in the economy, exactly one way to produce every good in the economy, or we have, somehow, settled on one such way per good;
 
* every good in the economy is produced by combining inputs in fixed, known proportions, with no possibility of substitutions, alternative methods, increasing (or decreasing) returns, etc.;
 
* we do not need to check whether we actually have sufficient resources to achieve the desired level of output with the given technology
 
However, it would be easy enough (linear time) to check, at the end, whether the required resources exceed available stocks, so the last point is not all that bad.
 
What is bad is completely assuming away having to chose what to make and having to chose how to make it.
That’s all interesting, but while I may care technically or in the long run, I don’t care in this head design. I am not after optimums. And I am not trying to compute the whole economy at once. And I do assume that the analysis has roughly figured out the goods and services to produce, the ongoing signals of need will refine them and add new ones, and the value systems for those goods and services will figure out the details.
 
I do like Cockshott’s wage proposals, and he also had another great idea: students should be paid for all educational work. But those are both utopian. More on utopian ideas below.
 
==Red Plenty Platforms==
 
Nick Dyer-Witheford surveys all of the proposals mentioned above, plus his own (at the end of these excerpts),
 
To bring the New Socialists up to date we
should instead refer to Fredric Jameson’s iconoclastic vision of WalMart as ‘the shape of a Utopian future looming through the mist’
(2009: 423). His point is that, if one for a moment ignores the gross
exploitation of workers and suppliers, Wal-Mart is an entity whose
colossal organizational powers model the planned processes
necessary to raise global standards of living. And as Jameson
recognizes, and other authors document in detail (Lichtenstein,
2006), this power rests on computers, networks and information. By
the mid 2000s Wal-Mart’s data-centers were actively tracking over
680 million distinct products per week and over 20-million
customer transactions per day, facilitated by a computer system
second in capacity only to that of the Pentagon.
 
[...]
 
Thus the trajectory of both information processing speeds and data
gathering capacities points to the suppression of the ‘socialist
calculation problem.’ However, to speak of planning in such
panoptic contexts is to inevitably invoke fears of omniscient state
control. The New Socialists come from a vanguard Marxist-Leninist
lineage, with a self-avowed ‘Jacobin’ centralist perspective
(Cockshott, Cottrell, & Dieterich, 2011). To consider how
cybernetic planning might be developed in more transparent and
participatory modes, we need to look to different communist
traditions.
 
[...]
 
Historically, the anti-statist tendency in Marxism has been largely
carried in a very different ‘worker council’ tradition, that, against the
powers of party and state has insisted on the role of workplace
assemblies as the loci of decision-making, organization and power.
In an essay antediluvian by digital standards, ‘Workers' Councils and
the Economics of a Self-Managed Society,’ written in 1957 but
republished in 1972, immediately after the Soviet crushing of
Hungary’s Workers Councils, Cornelius Castoriadis noted the
frequent failure of this tradition to address the economic problems
of a ‘totally self-managed society.’ The question, he wrote, had to be
situated ‘firmly in the era of the computer, of the knowledge
explosion, of wireless and television, of input-output matrices
abandoning ‘socialist or anarchist utopias of earlier years’ because
‘the technological infrastructures ... are so immeasurably different
as to make comparisons rather meaningless’ (Castoriadis, 1972: np).
 
Like the planners of Red Plenty, Castoriadis imagines an economic
plan determined with input-output tables and optimizing equations
governing overall resource allocation (e.g. the balance between
investment and consumption), but with implementation in the
hands of local councils. His crucial point, however, is that there
should be several plans available for collective selection. This would
be the mission of ‘the plan factory’, a ‘highly mechanized and
automated specific enterprise’, using ‘a computer’ whose ‘memory’
would ‘store the technical coefficients and the initial productive
capacity of each sector’ (Castoriadis, 1972: np). This central
workshop would be supported by others studying the regional
implications of specific plans, technological innovations, and
algorithmic improvements. The ‘plan factory’ would not determine
what social targets should be adopted; merely generate options,
assess consequences, and, after a plan has been democratically
chosen, up-date and revise it as necessary. Castoriadis would agree
with Raymond Williams’s (1983) later observation that there is
nothing intrinsically authoritarian about planning, providing there is
always more than one plan.
 
This early concept of cybernetic self-management is a precursor of a
more recent envisioning of post-capitalism, Michael Albert and
Robin Hahnel’s (1991) ‘Participatory Economics’ or ‘Parecon’. This
too emerges from a ‘workers council’ tradition, though from an
anarchist, rather than Marxist line of thought. Their work is famous
for its model of ‘decentralized participatory planning’ (Albert, 2003:
122), alternative to both market mechanisms and central planning.
Councils are, again, the basic societal units for democratic decision,
but in Parecon these include not just worker but consumer councils,
too. Resource allocation is determined by these organizations’ bids
for different levels of production and consumption, which over a
series of rounds of negotiation are progressively reconciled by
Iteration Facilitation Boards. At successive stages of the planning
process, worker and consumer councils are encouraged by the IFBs
to revise their proposals in knowledge of each other’s inputs, until
enough convergence is produced to put a few possible plans to a
vote.
 
[...]
 
Yet perhaps the idea of everyone watching mobile screens lest they
miss, not a Facebook poke, but voting the seventh iteration of the
participatory plan, duplicates unattractive features of everyday life in
high-tech capitalism. So we might speculate further, and suggest that
what decentralized collective planning really needs is not just
council media but communist agents: communist software agents.
 
Software agents are complex programmed entities capable of acting
‘with a certain degree of autonomy... on behalf of a user (or another
program)’ (Wikipedia, 2013b: np). Such agents manifest ‘goal-
direction, selection, prioritization and initiation of tasks’; they can
activate themselves, assess and react to context, exhibit aspects of
artificial intelligence, such as learning, and can communicate and
cooperate with other agents (Wikipedia, 2013b: np).
[...] the arena in which such
agents truly excel is in the financial sector, where high frequency
trading is entirely dependent on software ‘bots’ capable of
responding to arbitrage possibilities in milliseconds.
 
One can’t help but ask, however, what if software agents could
manifest a different politics? Noting that Multi-Agent System
models can be thought of as a means to answer problems of resource
allocation, Don Greenwood (2007: 8) has suggested they could be
geared toward solving the ‘socialist calculation problem’. As
planning tools, Multi-Agent Systems, he notes, have the advantage
over real markets that ‘the goals and constraints faced by agents can
be pre-specified by the designer of the model’ (Greenwood, 2007:
9). It is possible to design agents with macro-level objectives that
involve more than just the maximization of individual self-interest;
two ‘welfare’ principles that economists have experimented with
incorporating are equality and environmental protection
sustainability.
 
[...]


Within capital, automation threatens workers with unemployment
or production speed-up. If, however, there were no dominant
structural tendency for increases in productivity to lead to
unemployment or greater output without reduction in labour time,
automation could systematically yield to less time spent in formal
workplaces. In a communist framework that protected access to the
use value of goods and services, robotization creates the prospect of
a passage from the realm of necessity to freedom. It reintroduces the
goal – closed down both within the Stakhanovite Soviet experiment
and in the wage-raising trades unionism of the West – of liberating
time from work, with all this allows both in terms of human self-
development and communal engagement.


=Other Researchers=
Juliet Schor’s (1991) estimate, that if American workers had taken
gains won from productivity increases since the 1950s, not in wages
but in time off, they would by 2000 have been working a twenty
hour week.[u][v] [Added note: that seems like too many hours. Paul Goodman in 1950 estimated one day a week.] It indicates the scale of possible change. Proposals for a
‘basic income’ have recently figured in left politics. There are
certainly criticisms to be made of these insofar as they are advanced
as a reformist strategy, with the risk of becoming merely a
rationalized welfare provision supporting neoliberal precarity. But it
would be hard to envision a meaningful communist future that did
not institute such measures to acknowledge the reductions in
socially necessary labour time made possible by advances in science
and technology, destroying Hayek’s calculation problem by
progressively subtracting from it the capitalist ur-commodity, labour
power.
 
[...]
 
An abundant communist society of high automation, free software,
and in-home replicators might, however, as Fraise (2011) suggests,
need planning more than ever – not to overcome scarcity but to
address the problems of plenty, which perversely today threaten
shortages of the very conditions for life itself. Global climate change
and a host of interlinked ecological problems challenge all the
positions we have discussed to this point. Bio-crisis brings planning
back on stage, or indeed calculation – but calculation according to
metrics measuring limits, thresholds and gradients of the survival of
species, human and otherwise. Discussing the imperatives for such
ecosocialist planning, Michael Lowy (2009) points out how this
would require a far more comprehensive social steering than mere
‘workers control’, or even the negotiated reconciliation of worker
and consumer interests suggested by schemes such as Parecon.
Rather, it implies a far-reaching remaking of the economic systems,
including the discontinuation of certain industries, such as industrial
fishing and destructive logging, the reshaping of transportation
methods, ‘a revolution in the energy-system’ and the drive for a
‘solar communism’ (Lowy, 2009: np).
 
[...]


* Raul Espejo, former director of the cybersyn project, now living in Lincoln UK; http://www.syncho.com/
By revealing the contingency of conditions for species survival, and
the possibility for their anthropogenic change, such ‘knowledge
infrastructures’ of people, artifacts, and institutions (Edwards, 2010:
17) – not just for climate measurement, but also for the monitoring
of ocean acidification, deforestation, species loss, fresh water
availability – reveal the blind spot of Hayek’s catallaxy in which the
very grounds for human existence figure as an arbitrary ‘externality’.
So-called ‘green capital’ attempts to subordinate such bio-data to
price signals. It is easy to point to the fallacy of pricing non-linear
and catastrophic events: what is the proper tag for the last tiger, or
the carbon emission that triggers uncontrollable methane release?
But bio-data and bio-simulations also now have to be included in
any concept of communist collective planning. Insofar as that
project aims at a realm of freedom that escapes the necessity of toil,
the common goods it creates will have to be generated with cleaner
energy, and the free knowledge it circulates have metabolic
regulation as a priority. Issues of the proper remuneration of labor
time require integration into ecological calculations.


[...]


The Soviet experience, of which the
cyberneticians featured in Red Plenty were part, was only a narrow,
historically specific and tragic instantiation of this capability, whose
authoritarianism occludes the most crucial point in the Marxist
concept of planning, namely that it is intended as a means of
communal election of which, of a variety of trajectories, collective
human ‘species-becoming’ might follow (Dyer-Witheford, 2004).
A new cybernetic communism, itself one of these options, would, we
have seen, involve some of the following elements: use of the most
advanced super-computing to algorithmically calculate labour time
and resource requirements, at global, regional and local levels, of
multiple possible paths of human development; selection from these
paths by layered democratic discussion conducted across assemblies
that include socialized digital networks and swarms of software
agents; light-speed updating and constant revision of the selected
plans by streams of big data from production and consumption
sources; the passage of increasing numbers of goods and services
into the realm of the free or of direct production as use values once
automation, copy-left, peer-to-peer commons and other forms of
micro-replication take hold; the informing of the entire process by
parameters set from the simulations, sensors and satellite systems
measuring and monitoring the species metabolic interchange with
the planetary environment.


=Projects=
=Projects=
Line 51: Line 341:
==Current Projects==
==Current Projects==


#[[Cyberfilter]]
#[[Lorea]]
#[[Lorea]]


==Past Projects==
==Past Projects==


* [[Cybersyn]] ; [[Socialist Cybernetics in Allende’s Chile]]
* [[Cybersyn]] ; [[Socialist Cybernetics in Allende’s Chile]]
=Tools=
==[[Open Source Workflow Engines]]==
·      ProcessMaker [http://www.processmaker.com/key-features]
·      Joget [http://www.joget.org/workflow-software/]
·      FoxOpen [http://www.foxopen.net/About]
==[[Viable Systems Model]] Software==
Jon Walker:
* Jose Perez Rios in Madrid has this http://www.vsmod.org Which is for modelling and diagnosis.  Downloadable for free.    I've not used it but reports says it's difficult to use.
* SCiO ( bunch of cyberneticians in Manchester  -  I'm a member)  have something called an organisational maturity model ( again downloadable)  http://www.scio.org.uk/organisational-maturity-model which asks lots of questions and helps you to do a VSM diagnosis.
* Raul Espejo has Viplan which was developed after Chile and used extensively in his work since then  - also explains the VSM, guides you through a diagnosis and is downloadable with Raul's permission.
http://www.syncho.org


=Topics=
=Topics=
Line 67: Line 381:
#[[Cybernetic Socialism]] ; [[Towards a New Cybernetic Socialism]] ; [[Socialist Cybernetics in Allende’s Chile]]
#[[Cybernetic Socialism]] ; [[Towards a New Cybernetic Socialism]] ; [[Socialist Cybernetics in Allende’s Chile]]
#[[Cybernetics and Governance]]
#[[Cybernetics and Governance]]
#[[Red Cybernetics]]
==Market==
#[[End of the Market]]
#[[Self Managed Market Socialism]]
#[[Self-Managed Economy]]
==Planning==
#[[Collaborative Planning]]
#[[Decentrally Planned Economy]]
#[[Democracy and Economic Planning]]
#[[Democratic Planning]]
#[[Open Source Planning]]
#[[Participatory Planning]]
#[[Planned Economy]]
#[[Planning]]
#[[Planning through the Market]]




Line 83: Line 418:


#[[Democratic Technics]]
#[[Democratic Technics]]
#[[Economies of Integration]]
#[[Hint-Based Systems]]
#[[Hint-Based Systems]]
#[[Holoptism]] ; [[Anoptism]]
#[[Holoptism]] ; [[Anoptism]]
#[[Mutual Coordination of Production]]
#[[Negotiated Coordination]] ; [[Participatory Coordination]]
#[[Non-Market Calculation]] ; [[Problem of Economic Calculability]]
#[[Peer Production]] ; [[Production for Use]]
#[[Polyarchy]]
#[[Polyarchy]]
#[[Red Plenty Platforms]]
#[[Red Plenty Platforms]]
Line 93: Line 433:
=Documentation=
=Documentation=


* The Stafford Beer Archive at Liverpool John Moores University Digital Collections [http://digitool.jmu.ac.uk:8881/R/I9MEH14TXFDS7MT9T8FRXRBMU6SPUQT8S232QRNLB6TNR3JRUT-00050?func=collections&collection_id=1234&local_base=stb]


==Articles==
==Articles==


#[[Axiomatization of Socio-Economic Principles for Self-Organizing Institutions]]
#[[Axiomatization of Socio-Economic Principles for Self-Organizing Institutions]]
#[[Cybernetics of Governance and the Cybersyn Project]]
#[[Engineering Self-Organising Systems]]
#[[Red Plenty Platforms]]
#[[Red Plenty Platforms]]
#[https://blog.p2pfoundation.net/how-the-signals-used-by-capitalist-supply-chains-could-serve-a-mutual-coordination-economy/2016/02/10 How the Signals used by Capitalist Supply Chains could serve a Mutual Coordination Economy]


==Books==
==Books==


#[[Cybernetic Revolutionaries]]. Technology and Politics in Allende’s Chile. By Eden Medi [http://mitpress.mit.edu/books/cybernetic-revolutionaries] ; [http://www.cyberneticrevolutionaries.com/]
#[[Cybernetic Revolutionaries]]. Technology and Politics in Allende’s Chile. By Eden Medi [http://mitpress.mit.edu/books/cybernetic-revolutionaries] ; [http://www.cyberneticrevolutionaries.com/]
#The [[Cybernetic State]]. Javier Livas.
===Fiction===
#[[Red Plenty]]. Francis Spufford. 'Factional/fictional' account of the failed Soviet experiment at cybernetic planning.
#[[Red Plenty]]. Francis Spufford. 'Factional/fictional' account of the failed Soviet experiment at cybernetic planning.
#[[Synco]]


=Other Reference Material=
=Other Reference Material=


* section in the [[Commons Transition Plan]]: http://en.wiki.floksociety.org/w/Research_Plan#Mutual_coordination_mechanisms_in_the_new_.27ethical.27_enterpreneurial_coalitions:_Cybersin_redux_.3F
* section in the [[Commons Transition Plan]]: [https://wiki.p2pfoundation.net/Commons_Transition_Plan#Mutual_coordination_mechanisms_in_the_new_.27ethical.27_entrepreneurial_coalitions:_Cybersin_.5B14.5D_redux.3F Mutual coordination mechanisms in the new 'ethical' entrepreneurial coalitions]


[[Category:Commons Economics]]


[[Category:Commons Economics]]
[[Category:Mutual Coordination]]

Latest revision as of 05:35, 8 May 2017

= an initiative to share insight around non-market, non-state based mutual coordination in production and economics

Alternative Name: Cybernetic Economics

Name of the Group

1. David Potocnik:

"My original intention was to form a study group & redevelopment project on the ashes of the Cybersyn project.

Perhaps the name Cybernetic economics would be more fitting.

In this context, I'm looking fwd to seeing what you mean with "Mutual Coordination Economics" and "an initiative to share insight around non-market, non-state based mutual coordination in production and economics"

As far as this I personally

  • agree with the non-market
  • would not limit to non-state
  • emphasis on distribution guiding production


2. Michel Bauwens:

I have no objection to changing the name.

My own idea is: what pricing is to the market and planning is to the bureaucratic state, mutual coordination is to economics based on open and shared commons.



Participants

Other Researchers


Discussion

Introduction to the potential for Mutual Coordination of Physical Production through Peer Production

0. What market pricing is to capitalism and planning is to state-based production, mutual coordination is to commons-based peer production!

1. Today we have the emergence of a new proto-system of production, Commons-Based Peer Production in which contributors are free to contribute to a common pool of shareable knowledge, code and design, which may be associated through physical production in microfactories using distributed machinery such as 3D printing.

2. This emerging new system of value creation and distribution is not sustainable if contributors need to find work as labour for capital, so contributors need to be able to generate livelihoods for themselves, keeping the generation of surplus value within the sphere of the commons and its contributors.

3. To achieve this, we advocate the use of Commons-Based Reciprocity Licenses such as the Peer Production License. This allows for the creation of a non-capitalist 'counter' economy based on Open Cooperativism and other forms of an ethical economy. In this proposal, the commoners or peer producers, i.e. the contributors to the commons, are also cooperators of their own corporate entities, which create livelihoods and insure the surplus value remains within the commons. So, in between the sphere of the accumulation of the commons (open input, participatory process, commons-oriented output), and the sphere of capital accumulation, there is a intermediary sphere of cooperative production, which regulates physical production and the social reproduction of the commoners-cooperators.


4. The production of immaterial common pools is already regulated through mutual coordination and stigmergy, i.e. coordination based on open and transparent signals of what is needed by the system; but physical production cannot be coordinated without similar signals, i.e. the coordination of production through information. It is therefore a next logical step to advocate and practice, within the ethical entrepreneurial coalitions that coalesce around particular commons through their shared adherence to the commons-based licenses, to also practice open accounting and open supply-chains and logistics. This means that within these coalitions, physical production can also be coordinated through stigmergic signals; and negotiated coordination and even voluntary common planning can take place on the basis of the shared production information.

Typology of Other Approaches

Compiled and commented upon by Bob Haugen:

Parecon: Participatory Economics

From Wikipedia [1]:

Participatory economics, often abbreviated parecon, is an economic system based on participatory decision making as the primary economic mechanism for the allocation of the factors of production and guidance of production in a given society. Participatory decision-making involves the participation of all persons in decision-making on issues in proportion to the impact such decisions have on their lives. Participatory economics is a form of decentralized economic planning and socialism involving the common ownership of the means of production. The participatory economic system is proposed as an alternative to contemporary capitalism, as well as an alternative to central planning. This economic model is primarily associated with the proposals put forth by the political theorist Michael Albert and economist Robin Hahnel, who describe participatory economics as an anarchistic economic vision.

The underlying values that parecon seeks to implement are equity, solidarity, diversity, workers' self-management and efficiency (defined as accomplishing goals without wasting valued assets). The institutions of parecon include workers' and consumers' councils utilizing self-managerial methods for making decisions,balanced job complexes, remuneration based on individual effort, and participatory planning.

[...]

Albert and Hahnel argue that it is inequitable and ineffective to compensate people on the basis of their birth or heredity. Therefore, the primary principle of participatory economics is to reward for effort and sacrifice.[3] For example, mining work — which is dangerous and uncomfortable — would be more highly paid than office work for the same amount of time, thus allowing the miner to work fewer hours for the same pay, and the burden of highly dangerous and strenuous jobs to be shared among the populace.

Additionally, participatory economics would provide exemptions from the compensation for effort principle.[3] People with disabilities who are unable to work, children, the elderly, the infirm and workers who are legitimately in transitional circumstances, can be remunerated according to need. However, every able adult has the obligation to perform some socially useful work as a requirement for receiving reward, albeit in the context of a society providing free health care, education, skills training, and the freedom to choose between various democratically structured workplaces with jobs balanced for desirability and empowerment. The starting point for the income of all workers in participatory economics is an equal share of the social product. From this point, incomes for personal expenditures and consumption rights for public goods can be expected to diverge by small degrees reflecting the choices that individual workers make in striking a balance between work and leisure time, and reflecting the level of danger and strenuousness of a job as assigned by their immediate peers.


New Socialism

Source: [2]

As described by Nick Dyer-Witheford in Red Plenty Platforms : [3]

...its twenty-first century super-computer planning follows to the letter the logic of the late nineteenth century Critique of the Gotha Program (Marx, 1970), which famously suggests that at the first, ‘lower’ stage to communism, before conditions of abundance allow ‘to each according to his needs’, remuneration will be determined by the hours of socially necessary labour required to produce goods and services. In the capitalist workplace, workers are paid for the reproduction of the capacity to labour, rather than for the labour actually extracted from them; it is this that enables the capitalist to secure surplus value.

The elimination of this state of affairs, Cockshott and Cottrell contend, requires nothing less than the abolition of money—that is, the elimination of the fungible general medium of exchange that, through a series of metamorphoses of money in and out of the commodity form, creates the self-expanding value that is capital. In their new Socialism, work would be remunerated in labour certificates; an hour’s work could be exchanged for goods taking, on a socially average basis, an equivalent time to produce. The certificates would be extinguished in this exchange; they would not circulate, and could not be used for speculation. Because workers would be paid the full social value of their labour, there would be no owner profits, and no capitalists to direct resource allocation. Workers would, however, be taxed to establish a pool of labour-time resources available for social investments made by planning boards whose mandate would be set by democratic decisions on overall social goals.

[...]

Cockshott and Cottrell’s answer [to the Calculation Problem] involves new tools, both conceptual and technical. The theoretical advances are drawn from branches of computing science that deal with abbreviating the number of discrete steps needed to complete a calculation. Such analysis, they suggest, shows their opponents’ objections are based on ‘pathologically inefficient’ methods (Cockshott, in Shalizi, 2012).

The input-output structure of the economy is, they point out, ‘sparse’—that is to say, only a small fraction of the goods are directly used to produce any other good. Not everything is an input for everything else: yogurt is not used to produce steel. The majority of the equations invoked to suggest insuperable complexity are therefore gratuitous. An algorithm can be designed to short-cut through input-output tables, ignoring blank entries, iteratively repeating the process until it arrives at a result of an acceptable order of accuracy.

Shalizi takes up Cockshott’s proposals in another article responding to the criticisms of the first article cited above:

For Cockshott's algorithm, or any other linear solver, to be of real relevance here, we need to presume that

  • we have settled on exactly how much of every good (and service) we want the economy to produce, including indexing by time and space;
  • we have, for each good in the economy, exactly one way to produce every good in the economy, or we have, somehow, settled on one such way per good;
  • every good in the economy is produced by combining inputs in fixed, known proportions, with no possibility of substitutions, alternative methods, increasing (or decreasing) returns, etc.;
  • we do not need to check whether we actually have sufficient resources to achieve the desired level of output with the given technology

However, it would be easy enough (linear time) to check, at the end, whether the required resources exceed available stocks, so the last point is not all that bad.

What is bad is completely assuming away having to chose what to make and having to chose how to make it. That’s all interesting, but while I may care technically or in the long run, I don’t care in this head design. I am not after optimums. And I am not trying to compute the whole economy at once. And I do assume that the analysis has roughly figured out the goods and services to produce, the ongoing signals of need will refine them and add new ones, and the value systems for those goods and services will figure out the details.

I do like Cockshott’s wage proposals, and he also had another great idea: students should be paid for all educational work. But those are both utopian. More on utopian ideas below.

Red Plenty Platforms

Nick Dyer-Witheford surveys all of the proposals mentioned above, plus his own (at the end of these excerpts),

To bring the New Socialists up to date we should instead refer to Fredric Jameson’s iconoclastic vision of WalMart as ‘the shape of a Utopian future looming through the mist’ (2009: 423). His point is that, if one for a moment ignores the gross exploitation of workers and suppliers, Wal-Mart is an entity whose colossal organizational powers model the planned processes necessary to raise global standards of living. And as Jameson recognizes, and other authors document in detail (Lichtenstein, 2006), this power rests on computers, networks and information. By the mid 2000s Wal-Mart’s data-centers were actively tracking over 680 million distinct products per week and over 20-million customer transactions per day, facilitated by a computer system second in capacity only to that of the Pentagon.

[...]

Thus the trajectory of both information processing speeds and data gathering capacities points to the suppression of the ‘socialist calculation problem.’ However, to speak of planning in such panoptic contexts is to inevitably invoke fears of omniscient state control. The New Socialists come from a vanguard Marxist-Leninist lineage, with a self-avowed ‘Jacobin’ centralist perspective (Cockshott, Cottrell, & Dieterich, 2011). To consider how cybernetic planning might be developed in more transparent and participatory modes, we need to look to different communist traditions.

[...]

Historically, the anti-statist tendency in Marxism has been largely carried in a very different ‘worker council’ tradition, that, against the powers of party and state has insisted on the role of workplace assemblies as the loci of decision-making, organization and power. In an essay antediluvian by digital standards, ‘Workers' Councils and the Economics of a Self-Managed Society,’ written in 1957 but republished in 1972, immediately after the Soviet crushing of Hungary’s Workers Councils, Cornelius Castoriadis noted the frequent failure of this tradition to address the economic problems of a ‘totally self-managed society.’ The question, he wrote, had to be situated ‘firmly in the era of the computer, of the knowledge explosion, of wireless and television, of input-output matrices abandoning ‘socialist or anarchist utopias of earlier years’ because ‘the technological infrastructures ... are so immeasurably different as to make comparisons rather meaningless’ (Castoriadis, 1972: np).

Like the planners of Red Plenty, Castoriadis imagines an economic plan determined with input-output tables and optimizing equations governing overall resource allocation (e.g. the balance between investment and consumption), but with implementation in the hands of local councils. His crucial point, however, is that there should be several plans available for collective selection. This would be the mission of ‘the plan factory’, a ‘highly mechanized and automated specific enterprise’, using ‘a computer’ whose ‘memory’ would ‘store the technical coefficients and the initial productive capacity of each sector’ (Castoriadis, 1972: np). This central workshop would be supported by others studying the regional implications of specific plans, technological innovations, and algorithmic improvements. The ‘plan factory’ would not determine what social targets should be adopted; merely generate options, assess consequences, and, after a plan has been democratically chosen, up-date and revise it as necessary. Castoriadis would agree with Raymond Williams’s (1983) later observation that there is nothing intrinsically authoritarian about planning, providing there is always more than one plan.

This early concept of cybernetic self-management is a precursor of a more recent envisioning of post-capitalism, Michael Albert and Robin Hahnel’s (1991) ‘Participatory Economics’ or ‘Parecon’. This too emerges from a ‘workers council’ tradition, though from an anarchist, rather than Marxist line of thought. Their work is famous for its model of ‘decentralized participatory planning’ (Albert, 2003: 122), alternative to both market mechanisms and central planning. Councils are, again, the basic societal units for democratic decision, but in Parecon these include not just worker but consumer councils, too. Resource allocation is determined by these organizations’ bids for different levels of production and consumption, which over a series of rounds of negotiation are progressively reconciled by Iteration Facilitation Boards. At successive stages of the planning process, worker and consumer councils are encouraged by the IFBs to revise their proposals in knowledge of each other’s inputs, until enough convergence is produced to put a few possible plans to a vote.

[...]

Yet perhaps the idea of everyone watching mobile screens lest they miss, not a Facebook poke, but voting the seventh iteration of the participatory plan, duplicates unattractive features of everyday life in high-tech capitalism. So we might speculate further, and suggest that what decentralized collective planning really needs is not just council media but communist agents: communist software agents.

Software agents are complex programmed entities capable of acting ‘with a certain degree of autonomy... on behalf of a user (or another program)’ (Wikipedia, 2013b: np). Such agents manifest ‘goal- direction, selection, prioritization and initiation of tasks’; they can activate themselves, assess and react to context, exhibit aspects of artificial intelligence, such as learning, and can communicate and cooperate with other agents (Wikipedia, 2013b: np). [...] the arena in which such agents truly excel is in the financial sector, where high frequency trading is entirely dependent on software ‘bots’ capable of responding to arbitrage possibilities in milliseconds.

One can’t help but ask, however, what if software agents could manifest a different politics? Noting that Multi-Agent System models can be thought of as a means to answer problems of resource allocation, Don Greenwood (2007: 8) has suggested they could be geared toward solving the ‘socialist calculation problem’. As planning tools, Multi-Agent Systems, he notes, have the advantage over real markets that ‘the goals and constraints faced by agents can be pre-specified by the designer of the model’ (Greenwood, 2007: 9). It is possible to design agents with macro-level objectives that involve more than just the maximization of individual self-interest; two ‘welfare’ principles that economists have experimented with incorporating are equality and environmental protection sustainability.

[...]

Within capital, automation threatens workers with unemployment or production speed-up. If, however, there were no dominant structural tendency for increases in productivity to lead to unemployment or greater output without reduction in labour time, automation could systematically yield to less time spent in formal workplaces. In a communist framework that protected access to the use value of goods and services, robotization creates the prospect of a passage from the realm of necessity to freedom. It reintroduces the goal – closed down both within the Stakhanovite Soviet experiment and in the wage-raising trades unionism of the West – of liberating time from work, with all this allows both in terms of human self- development and communal engagement.

Juliet Schor’s (1991) estimate, that if American workers had taken gains won from productivity increases since the 1950s, not in wages but in time off, they would by 2000 have been working a twenty hour week.[u][v] [Added note: that seems like too many hours. Paul Goodman in 1950 estimated one day a week.] It indicates the scale of possible change. Proposals for a ‘basic income’ have recently figured in left politics. There are certainly criticisms to be made of these insofar as they are advanced as a reformist strategy, with the risk of becoming merely a rationalized welfare provision supporting neoliberal precarity. But it would be hard to envision a meaningful communist future that did not institute such measures to acknowledge the reductions in socially necessary labour time made possible by advances in science and technology, destroying Hayek’s calculation problem by progressively subtracting from it the capitalist ur-commodity, labour power.

[...]

An abundant communist society of high automation, free software, and in-home replicators might, however, as Fraise (2011) suggests, need planning more than ever – not to overcome scarcity but to address the problems of plenty, which perversely today threaten shortages of the very conditions for life itself. Global climate change and a host of interlinked ecological problems challenge all the positions we have discussed to this point. Bio-crisis brings planning back on stage, or indeed calculation – but calculation according to metrics measuring limits, thresholds and gradients of the survival of species, human and otherwise. Discussing the imperatives for such ecosocialist planning, Michael Lowy (2009) points out how this would require a far more comprehensive social steering than mere ‘workers control’, or even the negotiated reconciliation of worker and consumer interests suggested by schemes such as Parecon. Rather, it implies a far-reaching remaking of the economic systems, including the discontinuation of certain industries, such as industrial fishing and destructive logging, the reshaping of transportation methods, ‘a revolution in the energy-system’ and the drive for a ‘solar communism’ (Lowy, 2009: np).

[...]

By revealing the contingency of conditions for species survival, and the possibility for their anthropogenic change, such ‘knowledge infrastructures’ of people, artifacts, and institutions (Edwards, 2010: 17) – not just for climate measurement, but also for the monitoring of ocean acidification, deforestation, species loss, fresh water availability – reveal the blind spot of Hayek’s catallaxy in which the very grounds for human existence figure as an arbitrary ‘externality’. So-called ‘green capital’ attempts to subordinate such bio-data to price signals. It is easy to point to the fallacy of pricing non-linear and catastrophic events: what is the proper tag for the last tiger, or the carbon emission that triggers uncontrollable methane release? But bio-data and bio-simulations also now have to be included in any concept of communist collective planning. Insofar as that project aims at a realm of freedom that escapes the necessity of toil, the common goods it creates will have to be generated with cleaner energy, and the free knowledge it circulates have metabolic regulation as a priority. Issues of the proper remuneration of labor time require integration into ecological calculations.

[...]

The Soviet experience, of which the cyberneticians featured in Red Plenty were part, was only a narrow, historically specific and tragic instantiation of this capability, whose authoritarianism occludes the most crucial point in the Marxist concept of planning, namely that it is intended as a means of communal election of which, of a variety of trajectories, collective human ‘species-becoming’ might follow (Dyer-Witheford, 2004). A new cybernetic communism, itself one of these options, would, we have seen, involve some of the following elements: use of the most advanced super-computing to algorithmically calculate labour time and resource requirements, at global, regional and local levels, of multiple possible paths of human development; selection from these paths by layered democratic discussion conducted across assemblies that include socialized digital networks and swarms of software agents; light-speed updating and constant revision of the selected plans by streams of big data from production and consumption sources; the passage of increasing numbers of goods and services into the realm of the free or of direct production as use values once automation, copy-left, peer-to-peer commons and other forms of micro-replication take hold; the informing of the entire process by parameters set from the simulations, sensors and satellite systems measuring and monitoring the species metabolic interchange with the planetary environment.

Projects

Current Projects

  1. Cyberfilter
  2. Lorea

Past Projects


Tools

Open Source Workflow Engines

· ProcessMaker [4]

· Joget [5]

· FoxOpen [6]


Viable Systems Model Software

Jon Walker:

  • Jose Perez Rios in Madrid has this http://www.vsmod.org Which is for modelling and diagnosis. Downloadable for free. I've not used it but reports says it's difficult to use.
  • Raul Espejo has Viplan which was developed after Chile and used extensively in his work since then - also explains the VSM, guides you through a diagnosis and is downloadable with Raul's permission.

http://www.syncho.org

Topics

Cybernetics

  1. Cybernetic Communism
  2. Cybernetic Planning
  3. Cybernetic Self-Management
  4. Cybernetic Socialism ; Towards a New Cybernetic Socialism ; Socialist Cybernetics in Allende’s Chile
  5. Cybernetics and Governance
  6. Red Cybernetics


Market

  1. End of the Market
  2. Self Managed Market Socialism
  3. Self-Managed Economy


Planning

  1. Collaborative Planning
  2. Decentrally Planned Economy
  3. Democracy and Economic Planning
  4. Democratic Planning
  5. Open Source Planning
  6. Participatory Planning
  7. Planned Economy
  8. Planning
  9. Planning through the Market


Stigmergic

  1. Stigmergic Collaboration
  2. Stigmergic Revolution
  3. Stigmergic Dimensions of Online Creative Interaction
  4. Stigmergic Science
  5. Stigmergic Organization and the Economics of Information
  6. Stigmergy


Other

  1. Democratic Technics
  2. Economies of Integration
  3. Hint-Based Systems
  4. Holoptism ; Anoptism
  5. Mutual Coordination of Production
  6. Negotiated Coordination ; Participatory Coordination
  7. Non-Market Calculation ; Problem of Economic Calculability
  8. Peer Production ; Production for Use
  9. Polyarchy
  10. Red Plenty Platforms
  11. Socialism of the 21st Century - Heinz Dieterich: "To be successfull, socialism must match the cybernetic complexity of capitalist states."
  12. Value Accounting System
  13. Viable Systems Model

Documentation

  • The Stafford Beer Archive at Liverpool John Moores University Digital Collections [7]

Articles

  1. Axiomatization of Socio-Economic Principles for Self-Organizing Institutions
  2. Cybernetics of Governance and the Cybersyn Project
  3. Engineering Self-Organising Systems
  4. Red Plenty Platforms
  5. How the Signals used by Capitalist Supply Chains could serve a Mutual Coordination Economy

Books

  1. Cybernetic Revolutionaries. Technology and Politics in Allende’s Chile. By Eden Medi [8] ; [9]
  2. The Cybernetic State. Javier Livas.

Fiction

  1. Red Plenty. Francis Spufford. 'Factional/fictional' account of the failed Soviet experiment at cybernetic planning.
  2. Synco

Other Reference Material